分享
 
 
 

RFC1744 - Observations on the Management of the Internet Address Space

王朝other·作者佚名  2008-05-31
窄屏简体版  字體: |||超大  

Network Working Group G. Huston

Request for Comments: 1744 AARNet

Category: Informational December 1994

Observations on the Management of

the Internet Address Space

Status of this Memo

This memo provides information for the Internet community. This memo

does not specify an Internet standard of any kind. Distribution of

this memo is unlimited.

Abstract

This memo examines some of the issues associated with the current

management practices of the Internet IPv4 address space, and examines

the potential outcomes of these practices as the unallocated address

pool shrinks in size. Possible modifications to the management

practices are examined, and potential outcomes considered. Some

general conclusions are drawn, and the relevance of these conclusions

to the matter of formulation of address management policies for IPv6

are noted.

1. IntrodUCtion

The area eXPlicitly examined here is the allocatable globally unique

IPv4 address space. Explicitly this includes those address groups

uniquely assigned from a single comprehensive address pool to

specific entities which are then at liberty to assign individual

address values within the address group to individual hosts. The

address group is handled by the technology as a single network

entity.

At present these addresses are allocated to entities on a freely

available, first-come, first-served allocation basis, within the

scope of a number of administrative grounds which attempt to direct

the allocation process to result in rational use of the space, and

attempt to achieve a result of a level of equity of availability that

is expressed in a sense of multi-national "regions" [1].

In examining the current management policies in further detail it is

useful to note that the IPv4 address space presents a number of

attributes in common with other public space resources, and there are

parallels in an economic analysis of this resource which include:

- the finite nature of the resource

This attribute is a consequence of the underlying technology

which has defined addressed entities in terms of a 32 bit address

value. The total pool is composed of 2**32 distinct values (not

all of which are assignable to end systems).

- the address space has considerable market value

This valuation is a consequence of the availability and extensive

deployment of the underlying Internet technology that allows

uniquely addressed entities the capability to conduct direct end-

to-end transactions with peer entities via the Internet. The

parameters of this valuation are also influenced by considerations

of efficiency of use of the allocated space, availability of end

system based internet technologies, the availability of Internet-

based service providers and the resultant Internet market size.

- address space management is a necessary activity

Management processes are requires to ensure unique allocation and

fair Access to the resource, as well as the activity of continuing

maintenance of allocation record databases.

Increasing rates of Internet address allocation in recent years imply

that the IPv4 address space is now a visibly finite resource, and

current projections, assuming a continuation of existing demand for

addresses predict unallocated address space exhaustion in the next 6

- 12 years (rephrasing current interim projections from the IETF

Address Lifetime Expectancy Working Group). There are two derivative

questions that arise from this prediction. Firstly what is the

likely outcome of unallocated address space exhaustion if it does

occur, and secondly, are there corrective processes that may be

applied to the current address management mechanisms that could allow

both more equitable allocation and potentially extend the lifetime of

the unallocated address space pool. These two issues are considered

in the following sections.

2. Outcomes of Unallocated Address Space Exhaustion - No change in

current Address Management Policies

As the pool of available addresses for allocation depletes, the

initial anticipated outcome will be the inability of the available

address pool to service large block address allocation requests.

Such requests have already been phrased from various utility

operators, and the demand for very large address blocks is likely to

be a continuing feature of address pool management. It is noted that

the overall majority of the allocated address space is very

inefficiently utilised at present (figures of efficiency of use of

less than 1% are noted in RFC1466, and higher efficiency utilisation

is readily achievable using more recent routing technologies, such as

Variable Length Subnet Masks (VLSM) and disjoint subnet routing).

Given the continuing depletion of the unallocated address pool, and

the consequent inability to service all address allocation requests,

it is a likely outcome of interaction between those entities with

allocated address space and those seeking address allocation that

such allocation requests could be satisfied through a private

transaction. In this situation an entity already in possession of a

sufficiently large but inefficiently utilised allocated address block

could resell the block to a third party, and then seek allocation of

a smaller address block from the remaining unallocated address space.

The implication is that both address blocks would be more efficiently

utilised, although it is the entity which has large blocks of

allocated address space which would be the primary beneficiary of

such transactions, effectively capitalising on the opportunity cost

of higher efficiency of address block use.

Such reselling / trading opportunities which involve the use of the

unallocated address pool would in all likelihood be a short term

scenario, as the high returns from this type of trading would

increase the allocation pressure from the pool and act to increase

depletion rates as more pressure is placed to claim large address

blocks for later resale once such blocks are no longer available from

the unallocated pool.

Following exhaustion of the unallocated address pool a free trading

environment in address blocks is a probable outcome, where address

blocks would be bought and sold between trading entities. The

consequent market, if unregulated, would act to price address space

at a level commensurate with the common expectation of the market

value of addresses, trading at a price level reflecting both the

level of demand, the opportunity cost of more efficient address use,

and the opportunity cost of deployment of additional or alternate

internetworking technologies to IPv4. It is interesting to note that

within such an environment the registry (or whatever takes the place

of a registry in such an environment) becomes analogous to a title

Office, acting to record the various transactions to ensure the

continued accuracy of "ownership" and hence acts as a source of

information to the purchaser to check on the validity of the sale by

checking on the validity of the "title" of the vendor. This impacts

on the characteristic features of Internet address registries, which

effectively become analogous to "titles offices", which typically are

structured as service entities with "lodgement fees" used to fund the

action of recording title changes. Whether existing registries adapt

to undertake this new function, or whether other entities provide

this function is a moot point - either way the function is a

necessary adjunct to such a trading environment.

It is also anticipated that in an unregulated environment the trade

in address blocks would very quickly concentrate to a position of

address trading between major Internet providers, where a small

number of entities would control the majority of the traded volume

(market efficiency considerations would imply that traders with large

inventories would be more efficient within this trading domain). It

is also reasonable to expect that the Internet service providers

would dominate this trading area, as they have the greatest level of

vested interest in this market resource. This would allow the

Internet service provider to operate with a considerably greater

degree of confidence in service lifetime expectation, as the service

provider would be in the position of price setting of the basic

address resource and be able to generate an address pool as a hedge

against local address depletion for the provider's client base.

There is of course the consequent risk of the natural tendency of

these entities forming a trading cartel, establishing a trading

monopoly position in this space, setting up a formidable barrier

against the entry of new service providers in this area of the

market. Such a scenario readily admits the position of monopoly-

based service price setting. Compounding this is the risk that the

providers set up their own "title office", so that in effect the

major trading block actually controls the only means of establishing

legitimacy of "ownership", which in terms of risk of anti-competitive

trading practices is a very seriously damaged outcome.

Assuming a relatively low cost of achieving significantly higher

efficiency address utilisation than at present, then the resultant

market is bounded only by the costs of agility of renumbering. Here

renumbering would be anticipated to occur in response to acquisition

of a different address block in response to changing local address

requirements, and the frequency of renumbering may occur in cycles of

duration between weeks and years. Markets would also be constrained

by deployment costs, where local address trading within a provider

domain would have little cost impact on deployment services (as the

aggregated routing scenario would be unchanged for the provider and

the provider's peers) whereas trading in small sized blocks across

provider domains would result in increased operational service cost

due to increased routing costs (where efforts to create aggregated

routing entries are frustrated by the effects of address leakage into

other routing domains).

In examining this consequent environment the major technical outcome

is strong pressure for dynamic host address assignment services,

where the connection and disconnection of hosts into the Internet

environment will cause a local state change in allocated addresses

(which may in turn trigger consequent extended dynamic renumbering

from time to time to accommodate longer term address usage trends).

It is also reasonable to predict a strengthening market for dynamic

address translation technologies, as an alternate client strategy to

the purchase of large address blocks from the trading market (this

scenario is the use of a private, potentially non-unique address

space within the client network, and the dynamic translation of end

host addresses into a smaller unique Internet routed address pool to

support external end-to-end sessions), and also the strengthened

market for firewall boundary technologies which also admit the use of

private address space within the client domain.

While it is not possible to accurately predict specific outcomes, it

would appear to be the case that increasing overall efficiency of

address utilisation will be most visible only after unallocated

address pool exhaustion has occurred, as there is then a consequent

strong economic motivation for such activity across all the entire

Internet address space.

As perhaps a cautionary comment regarding evolutionary technologies

for IPv4, it would also appear to be the case that evolutionary

technologies will not assume a quantum increase in economic viability

simply because of unallocated address pool exhaustion. Such

technologies will only lever additional advantage over IPv4 once the

marginal cost of increased IPv4 address space deployment efficiency

exceeds the marginal cost of deployment of new technologies, a

situation which may not occur for some considerable time after

unallocated address pool exhaustion.

3. Modification of Current Internet Address Management Policies

The three major attributes of the current address allocation

procedures from the unallocated pool are "first come first served"

(FCFS) and allocation on a "once and for all" (OAFA) basis, and the

absence of any charge for address allocation (FREE).

As noted above, the outcomes of such a process, when constrained by

the finite quantity of the resource in question, ultimately leads to

a secondary market in the resource, where initially allocated

resources are subsequently traded at their market valuation. This

secondary trade benefits only those entities who established a

primary position from the unallocated pool, and it is noted with

concern that the optimal behaviour while the unallocated pool exists

is to hoard allocated addresses on the basis that the secondary

market will come into existence once the pool is exhausted. Such a

market does not benefit the original address management operation,

nor does it necessarily benefit the wider community of current and

potential interested parties in the Internet community.

It is also noted that the outcome of a free address allocation policy

is the vesting of the management of the address space to the larger

Internet Service Providers, on the basis that in the absence of end

client address allocation charging policies which have the capability

of ensuring an independent address management function, those

entities who have the greatest vested interest in the quality of the

address allocation and registration function will inevitably fund

such an operation in the absence of any other mechanism. The risk

within this scenario is that placing the major asset of any

communications medium into the sphere of interest of the current

entities trading within that medium acts to increase the risk of

anti-competitive monopolistic trading practices.

An alternate address management strategy is one of allocation and

recovery, where the allocation of an address is restricted to a

defined period, so that the allocation can be regarded as a lease of

the resource. In such an environment pricing of the resource is a

potential tool to achieve an efficient and dynamic address allocation

mechanism (although it is immediately asserted that pricing alone may

be insufficient to ensure a fair, equitable and rational outcome of

address accessibility and subsequent exploitation, and consequently

pricing and associated allocation policies would be a normative

approach to such a public resource management issue).

It is noted that pricing as a component of a public resource

management framework is a very common practice, where price and

policy are used together to ensure equitable access, efficient

utilisation and availability for reallocation after use. Pricing

practices which include features of higher cost for larger address

blocks assist with equitable access to a diversity of entities who

desire address allocation (in effect a scarcity premium), and pricing

practices can be devised to encourage provider-based dynamic address

allocation and reallocation environments.

In the same fashion as a conventional lease, the leasee would have

the first option for renewal of the lease at the termination of the

lease period, allowing the lease to be developed and maintain a

market value. Such pricing policies would effectively imply a

differential cost for deployment of a uniquely addressed host with

potential full Internet peering and reachability (including local

reachability) and deployment of a host with a locally defined (and

potentially non-unique) address and consequent restriction to local

reachability.

It is also observed that pricing policies can encourage efficient

address space utilisation through factors of opportunity cost of

unused space, balanced by the potential cost of host renumbering

practices or the cost of deployment of dynamic address allocation or

translation technologies.

There are a number of anticipated outcomes of a management mechanism

which including pricing elements for the IPv4 address space

Firstly current address space utilisation projections (anticipated

useful lifetime for the pool of unallocated addresses) would extend

further into the future due to the factors of cost pressure for more

efficient address utilisation, and the additional cost of issuing a

local resource with a globally unique address and the opportunity

cost of extravagant use of global addresses with purely local

domains.

Secondly dynamic host address binding technologies, and dynamic

network address translation technologies would be anticipated to be

widely deployed, based on the perceived cost opportunities of using

such technologies as an alternative to extensive static host address

binding using globally unique addresses. Use of such technologies

would imply further extension of the lifetime of the address pool.

Such pricing practices could be applied on a basis of all future

address allocations, leaving those entities with already allocated

address blocks outside of the lease mechanism. Alternatively such

previous allocations could be converted to leases, applying a single

management policy across the entire address space and accordingly

levering the maximal benefit from such pricing policies in terms of

maximising the lifetime of the address space and maximising the value

of the address space. In such a situation of conversion some level

of recognition of previous implicit OAFA allocation policies can be

offset through delay of conversion to lease and also through

conversion of such previously allocated addresses to the lease,

waiving the lease purchase costs in such cases.

4. Internet Environment Considerations

Pricing for IPv4 addresses as a component of the overall address

management framework is by no means a novel concept, and despite the

advantages such pricing policies may offer in terms of outcomes of

efficiency of utilisation, fair and equitable access, security of

allocation and consequent market value, and despite the address pool

exhaustion time offsets such policies offer, it is the undeniable

case that no explicit pricing policies have been successfully

introduced into the Internet address allocation processes to date.

There are two predominate reasons offered in this analysis. The

first is the somewhat uncertain nature of the exact origin of primary

ownership of the IPv4 address space, and the unallocated address pool

in particular. The address pool has been administered according to

policies drafted by the Internet Assigned Numbers Authority (IANA).

The policies drafted by IANA are effectively policies which are the

outcome of the same consensus seeking approach used within the

Internet Standards process, and it is noted that within such an

environment unilateral declarations of ownership and related

assertions of policy control have difficulty in asserting an

effective role within the Internet community and such declarations

are generally incapable of gathering consensus support (It can be

argued that "ownership" is not a relevant concept within this domain,

as the essential attribute of such address elements are their

uniqueness within the global domain, and such an attribute is only

feasible through common recognition of a coordinated and reliable

management environment rather than the historical origin of the

resource in question). Secondly there is no formal recognition of

the address space as being a shared international resource which sits

within the purview of national public resource management policies

and administrative entities of each nation, nor is there a

recognition of the address space as a private resource owned and

administered by a single entity.

Recent policy changes, whereby large segments of the unallocated

address pool have been assigned to international bodies on a regional

basis, with further assignment to bodies within national contexts,

have been undertaken with a constant address allocation policy of

FCFS, OAFA and FREE, and although some effort has been made to

increase the deployment efficiency through explicit allocation policy

enumeration, the general characteristics of address allocation are

unchanged to date (those characteristics being of course FCFS, OAFA

and FREE).

One potential scenario is to speculate that pricing processes imposed

by the address allocation agency are not feasible within the current

Internet environment to the extent that any such policies could

significantly motivate increased address deployment efficiency to the

levels required for longer term unallocated address pool lifetime

extension. The lack of capability to employ pricing as a managerial

mechanism, even to the extent of cost recovery of the allocation and

subsequent registry maintenance function has a number of possible

longer term outcomes:

a) such functions will be restructured and operated from duly

authorised national administrative bodies for each nation.

Here the observation that the address pool delegation sequence

within the current Internet environment has not to date been

aligned with recognised national public communications resource

administrative entities is an expression of the major problem

that the unallocated address pool is not recognised as being

intrinsically the same public resource entity as the radio

spectrum or the telephone number space. The consequence of

this mismatch between existing public resource management

structures and IPv4 address space management implies that

public operation for this activity on a national basis

is not a commonly observed attribute. The competency of such

established public resource management structures in managing

what continues to be a remarkably vibrant and dynamic

technology-influenced domain must be questioned. Potential

outcomes may possibly include a rational and equitable address

space management mechanism, but would also in all probability

include a cost of a heavy damping factor on further

technological innovation and refinement of the underlying

technology base upon which the address space is sited as a

longer term outcome.

b) such functions are operated (and/or funded) by Internet Service

Providers. This is a more common scenario at present in the

Internet IPv4 environment, and although such an operational

environment does admit the potential for adequate funding for

competent administration of the operation, the strong

association of these entities who have established interests in

the operation of enterprises based on the provision of services

across the address space (i.e., strong interest in exploiting

the address space) has a natural tendency to express domination

of the market by established interests, threatening fair access

to the common resource and threatening the open market of

deployment of the technology. It is reasonable to suggest that

such alignments are undesirable from a public policy

perspective.

c) such functions are inadequately funded to service the level of

activity, and / or administrated informally and consequently

managed poorly, and the essential attribute of reliable address

space management is not achieved.

It is noted that these issues are largely unresolved within the

Internet community today, and tensions between established and

incoming Internet Service providers over equitable access to the

unallocated address space pool are a consequent risk.

5. Concluding Observations

In the absence of the capability to price the management of the

Internet address space at administrative cost levels, let alone the

capability to set pricing of address leasing at prices which reflect

the finite nature of the resource and reflect (even in part) the

market value of the resource, as a component of overall common

address management practices, the most likely scenario is a

continuation of the FCFS, OAFA and FREE address management policies

until exhaustion of the unallocated address pool occurs.

It is perhaps a sad reflection of the conflict of short term

objectives and longer term considerations that the evident short term

motivations of ready and equitable access to the IPv4 address (which

were the motivational factors in determining the current Internet

address allocation policies) run the consequent risk of monopoly-

based restrictive trade and barrier-based pricing as a longer term

outcome of unallocated address space exhaustion.

While free address allocation and the adoption of policies which

include pricing components both ultimately produce an outcome of

strong pressure for increased address space utilisation efficiency,

the removal of the neutral presence of the unallocated address pool

does induce considerable risk of open market failure within the

Internet itself if free address allocation policies continue until

pool exhaustion has occurred.

Further strengthening of the current FCFS, OAFA and FREE address

allocation policies, in an effort to induce higher address

utilization efficiencies across the remaining address space is not a

viable address management strategy refinement, in so far as the

trading market will then commence before unallocated pool exhaustion,

trading in large address blocks which are precluded from such

strengthened address allocation policies.

The most negative ASPect of this are is that these processes will

erode levels of confidence in the self regulatory capability of the

Internet community, such that significant douBTs will be expressed by

the larger community the Internet process is one which is appropriate

for effective formulation of common administrative policy of one of

the core common assets of the Internet.

These outcomes can all be interpreted as policy failure outcomes.

The seriousness of these outcomes must be assessed in the terms of

the anticipated timeframe of such policy failure. Current

expectations of unallocated address pool lifetime of 6 - 12 years

does allow the Internet community some time to revisit their methods

of administrative process definition, but this observation is

tempered by the IPv6 process and by increasing levels of pressure on

the address space in terms of growth in address demand through growth

of deployment of the Internet itself.

It is perhaps an appropriate conclusion to acknowledge the

impediments of existing processes to admit any significant process or

policy change that would produce a more efficient and effective

address space management regime.

However it is this policy failure to efficiently utilise the IPv4

address space through inadequate address pool management policies,

rather than the exhaustion of the pool per se which is perhaps the

driving force to design and deploy an evolutionary technology to IPv4

which possesses as a major attribute a significantly larger address

space.

It is also appropriate to conclude that any outside observer of the

IPv6 refinement process will look to see if there is any evidence of

experiential learning in address management policies. If there is to

be a successor technology for IPv4 it would be reasonable to

anticipate that associated address pool management mechanisms show a

greater degree of understanding of public resource space management

capability in the light of this experience. If no such evidence is

forthcoming then there is no clear mechanism to instil sufficient

levels of consumer and industry confidence in such technologies in

such a way which would admit large scale public deployment,

irrespective of the technical attributes of the successor technology.

Such potential mechanisms may include pricing components irrespective

of the actual size of the address resource, given that the number's

uniqueness is a resource with inherent market value irrespective of

whether scarcity pricing premiums are relevant in such an address

space.

It is also appropriate to conclude that continuation of current

address space management policies run a very strong risk of

restrictive and monopoly-based trading in address space, with

consequence of the same trading practices being expressed within the

deployed Internet itself.

The immediate action considered to be most appropriately aligned to

both the interests of the Internet community and the broader public

community is to examine Internet address space management structures

which include pricing as well as policy components within the overall

management mechanism, and to examine the application of such

mechanisms to both the existing IPv4 address space, and to that of

any refinement or successor Internet technology base.

6. References

[1] Gerich, E., "Guidelines for Management of IP Address Space", RFC

1466, Merit Network, Inc., May 1993.

7. Security Considerations

Security issues are not discussed in this memo.

8. Author's Address

Geoff Huston

Australian Academic and Research Network

GPO Box 1142

Canberra ACT 2601

Australia

Phone: +61 6 249 3385

Fax: +61 6 249 1369

EMail: Geoff.Huston@aarnet.edu.au

 
 
 
免责声明:本文为网络用户发布,其观点仅代表作者个人观点,与本站无关,本站仅提供信息存储服务。文中陈述内容未经本站证实,其真实性、完整性、及时性本站不作任何保证或承诺,请读者仅作参考,并请自行核实相关内容。
2023年上半年GDP全球前十五强
 百态   2023-10-24
美众议院议长启动对拜登的弹劾调查
 百态   2023-09-13
上海、济南、武汉等多地出现不明坠落物
 探索   2023-09-06
印度或要将国名改为“巴拉特”
 百态   2023-09-06
男子为女友送行,买票不登机被捕
 百态   2023-08-20
手机地震预警功能怎么开?
 干货   2023-08-06
女子4年卖2套房花700多万做美容:不但没变美脸,面部还出现变形
 百态   2023-08-04
住户一楼被水淹 还冲来8头猪
 百态   2023-07-31
女子体内爬出大量瓜子状活虫
 百态   2023-07-25
地球连续35年收到神秘规律性信号,网友:不要回答!
 探索   2023-07-21
全球镓价格本周大涨27%
 探索   2023-07-09
钱都流向了那些不缺钱的人,苦都留给了能吃苦的人
 探索   2023-07-02
倩女手游刀客魅者强控制(强混乱强眩晕强睡眠)和对应控制抗性的关系
 百态   2020-08-20
美国5月9日最新疫情:美国确诊人数突破131万
 百态   2020-05-09
荷兰政府宣布将集体辞职
 干货   2020-04-30
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案逍遥观:鹏程万里
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案神机营:射石饮羽
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案昆仑山:拔刀相助
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案天工阁:鬼斧神工
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案丝路古道:单枪匹马
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案镇郊荒野:与虎谋皮
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案镇郊荒野:李代桃僵
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案镇郊荒野:指鹿为马
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案金陵:小鸟依人
 干货   2019-11-12
倩女幽魂手游师徒任务情义春秋猜成语答案金陵:千金买邻
 干货   2019-11-12
 
推荐阅读
 
 
 
>>返回首頁<<
 
靜靜地坐在廢墟上,四周的荒凉一望無際,忽然覺得,淒涼也很美
© 2005- 王朝網路 版權所有